Risks of economic disruption—in particular, interest rate hikes and major trade disputes—are receding, a positive sign for growth. But fiscal risk, including potential clashes over the federal budget and debt ceiling, remains.
To many economists, it seems as though US policymakers have designed economic policy to deliver weakness in 2020. But recent events may have blunted two of the three main policy initiatives that created that weakness. Deloitte’s economics team remains concerned about policy already in the pipeline, and we are not altering our scenario probabilities. But there may be some positive signs for the economy in the near term.
First, in just a few months, the Federal Reserve changed the emphasis and likely near-term path of policy. The September Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) projections showed that Fed officials were assuming that the long-run Fed funds rate would be at least 3.0 percent. That fell to 2.8 percent in the December meeting.1 At the January 31–February 1 meeting, the Open Market Committee did not raise rates, as expected. But members did change the committee’s statement to say that they would be “patient” in making policy—and removed a clause indicating that the Fed was likely to continue raising rates. On top of that, Fed Chairman Jerome Powell said at his press conference that the next rate move could be either up or down.2
Explore our Economics collection
Subscribe to receive the related content from Deloitte Insights
This is a significant change in the interest rate outlook. The Deloitte forecast now has only one interest rate increase in 2019, and long-term rates are half a percentage point lower in the current forecast than in the previous forecast released in December.3
Second, talks with China appear to be proceeding to a conclusion that will not alter the status quo too much. The Deloitte baseline always assumed that this would be the case. But it is beginning to look more likely than it did a few months ago. The prospects of further tariff increases seem to be receding as both Chinese and US negotiators seem relatively optimistic. The most likely outcome (one that has been reflected in the baseline) is a set of relatively small, cosmetic changes to the US–China trade regime.
That’s good news for short-term economic growth. We would not be surprised to see some additional investment spending if the prospect of a trade war became more remote. That would help underpin growth when and if US federal government spending drops off in the new fiscal year.
This means that two of the three significant risks for a slowing economy in 2020 have at least moderated. Unfortunately, one risk has not. That’s the fiscal risk. While the recent government shutdown is now history, the president's FY 2020 budget, like all recent presidential budgets, will probably be declared dead on arrival.4 But submitting one at least allows the House and Senate to begin the process of negotiating the appropriations bills.5 They likely won’t have much time—and the prospects of brinkmanship remain strong.
And then, of course, there is the debt ceiling. Officially, the temporary lifting of the ceiling goes away in March. US Treasury accountants then rely on “extraordinary measures” to allow full funding of government operations. By August—or perhaps September—unless the government once again lifts the ceiling, “extraordinary measures” disappear, and Treasury will need to begin defaulting on some payments.6
In the background is the slowdown in China and Europe. Chinese growth seems to be slowing, and Europe may well be on the verge of a recession already7—even before the possibility of a disruptive hard Brexit. The loss of sales abroad now joins the set of reasons why US growth is likely to slow, and why the US economy remains highly vulnerable to a recession.8
Our scenarios are designed to demonstrate the different paths down which the Trump administration’s policies and congressional action might take the American economy. Foreign risks have not dissipated, and we’ve incorporated them into the scenarios. But for now, we view the greatest uncertainty in the US economy to be that generated within the nation’s borders.
The baseline (55.0 percent probability): Consumer spending continues to grow. A pickup in foreign growth helps to tamp down the dollar and increase demand for US exports, adding to demand. Fiscal stimulus from the tax bill and the budget agreement pushes growth up in 2019 but is somewhat offset by the impact of US tariffs and foreign response. However, the US government comes to an arrangement with trading partners, and the tariffs are removed fairly quickly. A small increase in trade restrictions adds to business costs in the medium term, but this is offset by lower regulatory costs. Budget debates continue to add to uncertainty as Congress slowly decides to lift the debt ceiling and pass appropriations for FY 2020, but no further shutdowns occur. As the impact of stimulus fades and the economy feels the effect of higher interest rates, growth slows below potential in 2020.
Recession (25.0 percent): The economy weakens in late 2019 and early 2020 from the impact of tariffs and the withdrawal of stimulus as the additional spending from this year’s budget agreement goes away. With the economy already weak, a relatively small financial crisis pushes the economy into recession. The Fed and the European Central Bank act to ease conditions, and the financial system recovers relatively rapidly. GDP falls in the second half of 2019 and the first quarter of 2020, and then recovers.
Slower growth (10.0 percent): Business tax cuts induce little investment spending. Productivity growth becomes even more sluggish. Tariffs remain in place as the United States and its trading partners fail to agree on new global trade arrangements. The tariffs raise costs and disrupt supply chains. Businesses hold back on investments to restructure their supply chains because of uncertainty about future policy. The higher spending authorization from the budget bill translates only slowly into additional federal outlays, reducing the budget bill’s impact on the economy. GDP growth falls to less than 1.5 percent over the forecast period, while the unemployment rate rises.
Productivity bonanza (10.0 percent): Technological advances begin to lower corporate costs, as deregulation improves business confidence. Improved infrastructure boosts short-run demand and, in the long run, capacity and the productivity of private capital. Tariffs are short-lived and turn out to have a smaller impact than many economists expected. The economy grows 2.5 percent in 2019, with growth at 2.3 percent after 2021 while inflation remains subdued.
The household sector has provided an underpinning of steady growth for the US economy over the past few years. Consumer spending grew steadily even as business investment was weak, exports faced substantial headwinds, and housing stalled. But that’s unsurprising, since job growth has been quite strong. Even with relatively low wage growth, those jobs have helped put money in consumers’ pockets, enabling households to continue to increase their spending. The continued steady (if modest) growth in house prices has helped, too, since houses are most households’ main form of wealth.
For all the daily speculation about how political developments might affect consumer choices when it comes to spending decisions, political noise seems to be just that—in the background—to consumers who seem focused on their own situations. As long as job growth holds up and house prices keep rising, consumer spending will likely remain strong. And the tax cut, while modest for most consumers, bolstered their confidence that they can safely spend. More importantly, the tax bill’s fiscal stimulus has continued to tighten the job market. At some point, wages might begin to rise—and that could give consumer spending a further boost.
The medium term presents a different picture. Many American consumers spent the 1990s and ’00s trying to maintain spending even as incomes stagnated. But now they are wiser (and older, which is another challenge, as many baby boomers face imminent retirement with inadequate savings9). That may constrain spending and require higher savings in the future.
And although American households seem to face fewer obstacles in their pursuit of the good life than just a few years ago, rising income inequality could pose a significant challenge for the sector’s long-run health. For instance, low unemployment hasn’t alleviated many people’s economic insecurity: Four in 10 adults would be able to cover an unexpected US$400 expense only by borrowing money or selling something.10 For more about inequality, see Income inequality in the United States: What do we know and what does it mean?,11 Deloitte’s most recent examination of the issue.
The housing market has weakened. In fact, we might have seen the best of the recovery from the sector’s destruction in the 2007–09 crash. Housing starts at the current level of around 1.2 to 1.3 million may be the best we can get. A simple model of the market based on demographics and reasonable assumptions about the depreciation of the housing stock suggests that housing starts are likely to stay in the 1.1–1.2 million range. Starts are likely to fall as the economy weakens in the next year or two, and then gradually increase over the five-year horizon. Even the most optimistic view, however, does not allow for housing starts to return to anything like the 2 million-plus level registered in the mid-2000s.
Housing remains a smaller share of the economy than it was before the Great Recession, and that’s to be expected. In some ways, it’s a relief to realize that the sector has returned to “normalcy.” But with slowing population growth, housing simply can’t be a major generator of growth for the US economy in the medium and long run.
Some folks are pointing to the slowing housing market with alarm, remembering something about how the last recession was connected to a housing problem.12 It’s certainly not a happy sight, especially for anybody in the home construction business. But a construction decline didn’t cause the last recession: Construction began subtracting from GDP growth in the fourth quarter of 2005, two years before the recession, and GDP growth remained healthy. It was housing finance that ultimately created the crisis, not housing itself. Today, housing accounts for just under 4.0 percent of GDP (in 2005, it accounted for about 6.0 percent). The sector simply isn’t large enough to cause a recession—unless, once again, huge hidden bets on housing prices come to light.
While businesses were still reckoning with the implications of the tax bill for investment, the US government introduced additional uncertainty in a radical shift in international trade policy. Nor has budget uncertainty disappeared with the enactment of full appropriations for FY 2019. Policy uncertainty is one of the biggest potential roadblocks to strong investment spending.
Business investment soared in the first two quarters of 2018. However, it takes time for business decisions to result in new investment being put in place, suggesting that this investment spike was unlikely to have been a result of the tax bill passed at the very end of 2017. In Q3, investment spending growth almost stopped. And monthly data for construction and shipments of capital goods suggests that investment spending growth will remain slow in Q4. In truth, the cost of capital has been at historic lows over the past decade, but many businesses have remained reluctant to take advantage to raise investment. So cutting the cost of capital further by slashing the tax rate may have at best a modest impact. While our forecast is optimistic about the potential impact of the tax reform bill, that amounts to likely adding only 0.1 to 0.2 percentage points to GDP growth in the next few years.
The imposition of tariffs on a wide variety of goods—and foreign retaliation in the form of tariffs on American products—creates a large degree of uncertainty, particularly for manufacturing firms. Some CEOs may face a painful medium-term dilemma: deciding whether their businesses need to rebuild their supply chains. Industries such as automobile production have developed intricate networks across North America and are reaching into Asia and Europe, based on the long-standing assumption that materials and parts can be moved across borders with little cost or disruption. There is some evidence that a substantial number of business leaders are beginning to think about postponing investment: The Atlanta Fed found in early August that some 30.0 percent of manufacturing firms are reassessing capital expenditure plans because of uncertainty about tariffs.13
And fiscal policy uncertainty didn’t disappear with the passing of the final appropriations bills for FY 2019. It seems as though each step taken in the direction of reducing fiscal uncertainty leads to yet another deadline. The next two are the need to raise the debt ceiling—officially in March, but likely not until the summer—and the need to pass the appropriations bills for FY 2020 by the end of September. Policy uncertainty is therefore likely to continue to weigh on investment decisions.
The Fed walking back its stated interest-rate hikes is one piece of good news for business investment. Corporate borrowing costs will remain low, and the Deloitte forecast for investment is a little higher this quarter as a result. However, since the constraint on business investment has not been costs, the impact here may be more modest than some anticipate.
The Deloitte economics team remains optimistic about investment in the medium term, since the US economy remains a fundamentally good place to invest. But business investment plays a key role in differentiating between Deloitte’s baseline, slow-growth, and productivity-bonanza scenarios. If policy uncertainty does indeed weaken business spending, the likelihood of the slow-growth scenario would substantially increase.
Over the past few decades, business—especially manufacturing—has taken advantage of generally open borders and cheap transportation to cut costs and improve global efficiency. The result is a complex matrix of production that makes the traditional measures of imports and exports somewhat misleading. For example, in 2017, 37.0 percent of Mexico’s exports to the United States consisted of intermediate inputs purchased from ... the United States.14
Recent events appear to be placing this global manufacturing system at risk. The United Kingdom’s increasingly tenuous post-Brexit position in the European manufacturing ecosystem,15 along with ongoing negotiations to replace the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), may slow the growth of this system or even cause it to unwind.
But the biggest challenge now facing the global trading system is the imposition of tariffs and retaliatory tariffs. The process began with US tariffs on solar panels and washing machines and now encompasses a wide variety of US imports from China and other countries. And those countries have responded, leaving an increasing amount of US exports subject to foreign retaliatory tariffs. There is some positive evidence that President Trump may be willing to reach an agreement with China, which might alleviate some of the impact of these trade restrictions.16 At the same time, however, the administration is now considering putting a tariff on European exports of automobiles to the United States for “security reasons.”17 That suggests that agreement in one area will simply lead to more uncertainty in other areas, and on a global basis, trade policy may continue to be an important reason for slowing growth.
Whether this qualifies as a “trade war” is a semantic question—the real issue is the uncertainty about the tariffs and the US government’s goals in imposing the tariffs. White House trade adviser Peter Navarro argues that the tariffs are necessary to reduce the US trade deficit and to help the United States retain industries such as steel production for strategic reasons.18 This suggests that tariffs in “strategic” industries could be permanent. But Commerce Secretary Wilbur Ross has stated that the goal is to force US trading partners to lower their own barriers to American exports.19 That suggests that the administration intends the tariffs to be a temporary measure to be traded for better access to foreign markets.
The apparent lack of clarity in the administration’s stated objectives with regard to tariffs adds to the overall uncertainty involved with the escalating actions that began in the spring. In the short run, uncertainty about border-crossing costs may reduce investment spending. Businesses may be reluctant to invest when facing the possibility of a sudden shift in costs. Deloitte’s slow-growth scenario assumes that the impact is large enough to affect overall business investment.
The challenge that companies face is that a significant change in border-crossing costs—as would occur if the United States withdrew from NAFTA without adopting its replacement, United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA), or made tariffs on Chinese goods permanent—could potentially reduce the value of capital investment put in place to take advantage of global goods flows. Essentially, the global capital stock could depreciate more quickly than our normal measures would suggest. In practical terms, some US plants and equipment could go idle without the ability to access foreign intermediate products at previously planned prices.
With this loss of productive capacity would come the need to replace it with plants and equipment that would be profitable at the higher border cost. We might expect gross investment to increase once the outline of a new global trading system becomes apparent.
In the longer term, a more protectionist environment will likely raise costs. That’s a simple conclusion to be drawn from the fact that globalization was largely driven by businesses trying to cut costs. How those extra costs are distributed depends a great deal on economic policy—for example, central banks can attempt to fight the impact of lower globalization on prices (with a resulting period of high unemployment) or to accommodate it (allowing inflation to pick up).
The current account is determined by global financial flows, not trade costs.20 Any potential reduction in the current account deficit is likely to be largely offset by a reduction in American competitiveness through higher costs in the United States, lower costs abroad, and a higher dollar. All four scenarios of our forecast assume that the direct impact of trade policy on the current account deficit is relatively small.
Adding to the problems in the trade sector, growth in Europe and China has clearly slowed. These are two of the three regions that drive the global economy (the third is the United States). Slow growth abroad is very likely to translate into slower growth in US exports and perhaps a higher dollar (slowing export growth further). That’s an important contributor to downside risk for the American economy.
Brexit is an immediate issue in the short run, although it does not affect the medium- or long-term outlook that much. A hard Brexit is unlikely to significantly affect US sales abroad directly. But it could help soften overall European economic growth even further—providing yet another headwind for American exporters.
Government spending provides an unusual source of volatility in the Deloitte forecast. The tax bill passed in late 2017 and the budget bill passed in early 2018 together created a large stimulus—over 2.0 percent of GDP, by Deloitte calculations—in 2019. As the stimulus ends, that government spending will likely start falling in late 2019 and through 2020. This drag on the economy is large enough to slow growth substantially. The Deloitte baseline forecast sees GDP growth at just 1.1 percent in 2020, quite a bit below potential.
The tax bill’s long-run impact on the economy’s capacity remains a matter of debate, with estimates ranging from no real change after a decade (Tax Policy Center) to 2.8 percent, or almost 0.3 percentage points annually (Tax Foundation).21 In this forecast’s five-year horizon, the supply-side impact is likely too small to be noticeable.
The midterm elections, as expected, returned a Democratic House and Republican Senate, likely taking major economic policy changes off the table until after 2020.22 The split Congress may also complicate budget decision-making over the next couple of years—although the budget has been a source of uncertainty even as Congress has been under single-party control recently. The recent shutdown demonstrates the potential of the current political environment to intensify policy uncertainty.
And it seems that, as Congress and President Trump reach agreement on one budget issue, another deadline immediately looms. In this case, the final passage of FY 2019 appropriations leads immediately into the challenge of the debt ceiling expiration. The US government is currently operating under a temporary suspension of the debt ceiling, which ends on March 2. As it has done in the past, the Treasury Department will likely employ “extraordinary measures” for some months, but Congress must meet a hard deadline sometime in, most likely, late summer. At that point, another deadline will loom: the beginning of FY 2020 (at the beginning of October) and the need to pass appropriations bills by then. Continued deadlines have created permanent uncertainty about US government finances.
There may be room for some positive surprises. In theory, increased infrastructure spending has bipartisan support. However, obtaining agreement on this may be difficult because the Trump administration and the House leadership have very different views of how, specifically, to proceed on infrastructure. Our baseline assumes no infrastructure plan, while the productivity-bonanza scenario assumes some additional government spending as well as additional productivity from these investments in the medium and long runs.
After years of belt-tightening, many state and local governments are no longer actively cutting spending. However, many state budgets remain constrained by questions around the effects of new federal tax policy23 and the need to meet large unfunded pension obligations,24 so state and local spending growth will likely remain low over this forecast’s five-year horizon.
Pressure is building for increased spending in education, as evidenced by the ongoing public teacher protests in several states.25 With education costs accounting for about a third of all state and local spending, a significant upturn in this category could create some additional stimulus—or could require an increase in state and local taxes.
If the American economy is to effectively produce more goods and services, it will need more workers. Many potential employees remain out of the labor force, having left in 2009, when the labor market was challenging. But they are returning. The labor force participation rate for 24–54-year-old workers has been rising since the middle of 2015 and is, as of January, 82.4 percent. But this is still below the peak of over 84.0 percent reached in the late 1990s, suggesting that there are a considerable number of workers who can be enticed back into the labor market as conditions improve. Our baseline forecast reflects that possibility.
Meanwhile, the labor force participation rate for over-65s has flattened out. It’s still much higher than the historical average—and it is certainly possible that, with better labor market conditions, employers can entice more over-65s back into the labor force as well.
But a great many people are still on the sidelines and have been out of steady employment for years—long enough that their basic work skills may be eroding. Are those people still employable? So far, the answer has been “yes,” as job growth continues to be strong without pushing up wages. Deloitte’s forecast team remains optimistic that improvements in the labor market will prove increasingly attractive to potential workers, and labor force participation is likely to continue to improve accordingly. However, we are now close enough to full employment that average monthly job growth is likely to drop from the current 200,000 per month to about 100,000 per month in the next two years, even if the economy remains healthy.
In the longer run, demographics are slowing the growth of the population in prime labor force age. As boomers age, lagging demographic growth will help slow the economy’s potential growth. That’s why we foresee trend GDP growth below 2.0 percent by 2021: Even with an optimistic view about productivity, we expect that slow labor force growth will eventually be felt in lower economic growth.
Immigration reform might have a marginal impact on the labor force. According to the Pew Research Center, undocumented immigrants make up about 4.8 percent of the total American labor force.26 Immigration reform that restricts immigration and/or increases the removal of undocumented workers might create labor shortages in certain industries, such as agriculture, in which some a quarter of workers are unauthorized,27 and construction, in which an estimated 15.0 percent of workers are unauthorized.28 But it would likely have little significant impact at the aggregate level.
Interest rates are among the most difficult economic variables to forecast because movements depend on news—and if we knew it ahead of time, it wouldn’t be news. The Deloitte interest rate forecast is designed to show a path for rates consistent with the forecast for the real economy. But the potential risk for different interest rate movements is higher here than in other parts of our forecast.
Short-term interest rates may not rise much beyond present levels. In its January–February meeting, the FOMC changed its statement to suggest that further increases anytime soon were unlikely. Many Fed officials seem to have come to the conclusion that short-term interest rates are at a “neutral” level—the rate that is consistent with full employment and stable inflation. FOMC members’ central estimate for the longer-run value of the Fed funds rate is now just 2.8 percent. We expect the Fed to hike rates just once this year—most likely, at the June meeting, when we expect some strong data. But in the fall, data is likely to suggest a weakening economy, and the Fed has clearly signaled that it won’t raise rates under those conditions. We do expect the Fed to continue to let its inventory of long-term assets shrink at a slow rate. A significant shock to the economy could cause the Fed to start buying long-term assets again, but this is not in our baseline.
As the economy approaches full employment and the possibility of higher inflation increases, long-term interest rates could rise as well—and perhaps even rise faster. That’s not necessarily a bad thing. It’s part of the “return to normal” that the US economy is experiencing.
The spread between long- and short-term rates has been remarkably small lately. It may remain that way for a while, but eventually, the forecast expects the spread to widen back to about 1.0 to 1.5 percentage points. That’s consistent with historical experience, but does suggest that long-term rates are likely to rise to 3.5 percent or even 4.0 percent once the economy passes the period of weakness we expect in 2020.
It’s been a long time since inflation has posed a problem for American policymakers. Could inflation break out as the economy reaches full employment? Many economists are increasingly wondering about this, as it becomes evident that something is amiss in the standard inflation models. These models posit that, since labor accounts for about 70.0 percent of business costs, the state of the labor market should drive overall inflation. US labor markets appear to be tightening, but wages have failed to rise accordingly or even keep pace with inflation. Real wages for nonsupervisory employees have risen just 0.1 percent annually in the last two years, and unit labor costs have been flat for the last two quarters. As long as businesses don’t face increasing costs, it’s hard to see what could drive a sustained rise in goods and services prices.
But it’s also quite possible that the economy simply hasn’t hit full employment. Despite unemployment dipping below 4.0 percent, the labor force participation rate for prime-age workers remains about two points below the rate before the financial crisis. Two percent of the prime working-age population suggests that about 4 million more people could be enticed into the labor force under the right conditions. Whether those people are really available is unclear, and many economists are debating the issue fiercely.29 The combination of low labor-cost growth and continued high employment growth suggests that people are likely being enticed back into the labor market.
At some point, however, the combination of the tax cut and spending increase could create some shortages in both labor and product markets and, as a result, some inflation. And tariffs are something of a wild card. So far, most of the tariffs have been on intermediate products, and the price increases from these will be relatively modest and take time to work through the system. A large increase in tariffs on consumer goods would likely cause a fast, one-time rise in consumer prices, particularly for products such as apparel and furniture. Interpreting inflation data under those circumstances could be tricky. And if that rise sparks wage hikes to maintain real wages—a possibility at current unemployment rates—inflation could indeed tick up.
A return to 1970s-style inflation is about as likely as polyester leisure suits coming back into style. But it would not be surprising in these circumstances to see the core CPI rise to above 2.5 percent. Our forecast expects timely Fed action to prevent inflation from rising too much, but the price (of course) is higher interest rates.